A feature story for this week’s New York Times Magazine is titled The Creative Apocalypse That Wasn’t. In the article, writer Steven Johnson concludes that neither the economic nor the cultural losses in the creative industries, which were predicted to result from the digital revolution, have come to pass. Just as lesser pundits have previously declared in blogs and industry PR pieces, Johnson tells readers the picture is actually rosier than ever for both creators and consumers since the disruption known as Napster. And of course some of those lesser pundits (e.g. Bob Lefsetz) have been quick to leap onto Johnson’s coattails and say, “See? Told ya so!”
Setting aside the exaggerated title of the article — I don’t remember anyone seriously predicting a “creative apocalypse” — Johnson has certainly made an effort to approach the question more scientifically and more complexly than most — or at least it will appear this way to readers based on his tone and some of the culturally-sensitive questions he rightly poses. But the tricky thing about this article, as I see it, is that its main thesis is a bit of a moving target supported by a variety of statements that, in themselves, want far more complex analysis than Johnson either realizes or is willing to admit.
If we strip away some of the color and simply look at the assertions being made, then the basic structure of the article reveals an important fallacy. First Johnson states that most of the evidence of harm done to creators in the digital age is anecdotal, and this is partly true — although anecdotes from professionals should not be misconstrued as mere random complaining. So, to get beyond the anecdotal, Johnson then cites macroeconomic data, compiled by the Labor Department, most of which suggests a big-picture view that creative people in all media are doing better than they were a decade ago. But, having previously scorned the anecdotal negative, Johnson then cherrypicks bits and pieces of the anecdotal positive — some of which he misrepresents — in order to support his interpretation of the economic data he cites.
Writers, like Paul Resnikof of Digital Music News, have previously commented on some of the flaws in the kind of data Johnson cites, demonstrating how big numbers can go up without necessarily benefiting the majority of workers in a particular sector. It can be a bit like saying, The good news is there are more jobs this quarter, when the hidden bad news is that an individual needs two of those jobs just to meet the cost of living. Or to put it another way, if ten musical superstars were to generate eighty-billion in revenue, this does not mean most middle-class musicians will share the prosperity of an eighty-billion-dollar industry. So, one must be careful with macroeconomic data, and Johnson acknowledges this, when he writes:
Could the surge in musicians be accompanied by a parallel expansion in the number of broke musicians? The income data suggests that this just isn’t true. According to the O.E.S., songwriters and music directors saw their average income rise by nearly 60 percent since 1999. The census version of the story, which includes self-employed musicians, is less stellar: In 2012, musical groups and artists reported only 25 percent more in revenue than they did in 2002, which is basically treading water when you factor in inflation. And yet collectively, the figures seem to suggest that music, the creative field that has been most threatened by technological change, has become more profitable in the post-Napster era — not for the music industry, of course, but for musicians themselves. Somehow the turbulence of the last 15 years seems to have created an economy in which more people than ever are writing and performing songs for a living.
But even if the numbers do lead to the conclusion Johnson wants us to draw — and it’s not clear that they do — I would point out that this is an example of the shifting thesis I referred to above. Because these numbers, gathered from such a broad perspective, do not actually tell us anything about the effect the “digital economy” (good or bad) has had on the creative market, let alone offer any indicators as to what we might expect for the near future — and this is almost more important than where things stand right now.
At best, one might conclude that coincident with the development of Web 2.0, general revenues in the creative sectors have risen, but these data alone do not reveal any specific information that justifies dismissing all the anecdotal evidence from countless creators who are telling us that, in general, the threats outweigh the opportunities. And so, it is not surprising that, after presenting these revenue data, Johnson himself resorts to a litany of familiar, yet incomplete, anecdotes about all the good news out there. But before addressing some of these, I’d like to return to the matter of thesis and remind ourselves what the underlying logic is behind the question that’s really being asked.
Johnson begins his article by citing Napster, which is arguably the beginning of piracy as we know it; and piracy was, and continues to be, foundational to many of the most dire predictions about the future of the creative economy. But having set the stage with Napster (and a little dig at Lars Ulrich), Johnson then transitions to a broad analysis of “success” in the creative marketplace, essentially leaving piracy out of the discussion. Hence, there is a little sleight of hand going on here because the argument he is supporting, either intentionally or not, is one often used to assert this general claim: That although models based on creator ownership of works are outdated, there are ample new and better models available, if creators would just recognize them. For instance, setting aside all the crazy, ideological bullshit about piracy, the economic argument that has been made, and which Johnson is fundamentally supporting, boils down to the following:
- Yes, piracy created an expectation of free and very low-cost access, and it decimated actual sales of media to consumers. This also led to legal platforms like YouTube getting away with monetizing infringed works for years. But …
- The same technologies that enabled piracy and YouTube-type, montetized infringement have also opened up unprecedented opportunities for creators to earn revenue from new streams. So …
- Smart creators will seize these new opportunities and stop worrying about piracy and other infringements. Because …
- The concept of copyrights for creators is an anachronism being clung to solely by legacy industry, which is incapable of adapting to a future that is chockfull of the aforementioned opportunities for individual creators.
So, it seems to me that any economic analysis regarding the sustainability of creators should either prove or disprove this basic argument. And I will assert that Johnson fails even to fully address this matter because his article consistently strays from analysis as to whether or not the piracy-to-freemium narrative has been harmful, neutral, or beneficial to the market; and whether or not digital technology and the design of Web 2.0 have legitimately spawned enough new opportunity to overcome the market shift away from selling media direct to consumers.
Because, anecdotal though it may be, plenty of seasoned and younger creators of every size and type can tell you that many of the “new opportunities” cited by outside observers are either not new; or they are second-tier substitutes for the revenue that has been lost; or they are simply other lines of business that have little or nothing to do with the core creative works. Johnson is as guilty in this article as many tech-utopians, who like to point to what’s left for creators (e.g. touring for musicians), now that sales are gone. Unfortunately, this is a bit like telling someone, Dude, I know they stole your car, but at least you still have your skateboard.
Moreover, many of the “new” revenue streams to which Johnson refers are either precarious, unproven, or short-lived in many cases. For instance, he cites the unprecedented opportunity for a musician to share ad revenue via YouTube, but he seems to have missed several recent memos that might indicate why this model may never be a sustainable driver.
The first of these memos would be Zöe Keating’s explanation of what it’s like for an indie musician to transition from happily earning revenue via YouTube’s Content ID system to the more recent offer-she-can’t-refuse known as the Music Key contract, which in fact voids the Content ID account of any musician who does not sign. The second memo would be a case like that of Jack Douglas, whose satirical videos are supposed to earn him ad revenue on YouTube, but they don’t earn him anything when someone re-uploads his videos to Facebook. (Not that it isn’t funny to watch Google lose revenue as an example of its own anti-copyright agenda, but I digress.) And perhaps the most compelling memo Johnson didn’t get would include recent reports that indicate Web advertising itself may be in serious crisis as a value proposition across the entire industry. Each of these three topics is a complex conversation unto itself, which would qualify some of Johnson’s blue-sky conclusions. And these are just the first that come to mind in response to just one of his anecdotal examples of how well one class of creators is supposedly doing.
There are, of course, too many instances in this article in which Johnson merely rattles off highlights (e.g. the current golden age in TV production) as though we’re meant to conclude without looking at any details that the “digital economy” has either helped, or at least not harmed, a given sector. And, unfortunately, as other outside commentators have done before, Johnson cites the “lower cost of production,” thanks to digital technology, as an opportunity to maximize revenues for creators. But as I have pointed out in the past, while low-cost digital tools have lowered the barriers to entry for new creators, they have not necessarily lowered the cost of all production, depending on the medium and nature of the products.
Anyone who knows production — and this is most especially true for filmed entertainment — will tell you that the “digital technology lowers cost” talking point is a half-truth at best, and a rather cynical one because it overlooks the human effort, which hasn’t really changed all that much in most cases. For instance, most movies and TV that people seem to love — not to mention justify stealing — is produced with thousands of hours of highly-skilled labor, the cost of which has nothing to do with the digital tools being used to create or distribute works. And, in many cases, digital technology has actually increased those working hours rather than decreased them.
And I have to say that some of Johnson’s anecdotal evidence of good news are so tangential to his thesis as to be inscrutable, like when writes the following:
Think of that signature flourish of 2000s-era television artistry: the exquisitely curated (and usually obscure) song that signals the transition from final shot to the rolling credits. Having a track featured during the credits of ‘‘Girls’’ or ‘‘Breaking Bad’’ or ‘‘True Blood’’ can be worth hundreds of thousands of dollars to a songwriter. (Before that point, the idea of licensing a popular song for the credits of a television series was almost unheard-of.)
Surely, Johnson knows that licensing songs for filmed entertainment is not a new thing. And while it is true that the current, creative trend to synch various, thematically appropriate tracks to the end credits of shows is a nice opportunity for music creators, these deals have no direct relationship with the “digital economy” one way or another. Hence, Johnson is creating a distraction by identifying a revenue stream — a licensing agreement — between film producers and music creators, which neither supports nor rejects his overall point. If anything, he skips over the fact that the indirect impact of the free-media mindset has generally driven the value of creative works down to the extent that creators are continuously asked either to work — or allow the use of their works — for free or for very low rates. If anything, this effect on the market would seem to shrink the opportunity for musicians to make a living by licensing works, rather than expand them. But, again, my larger point is that each of the examples Johnson hauls into his net of good tidings begs far more in-depth analysis on a case-by-case basis.
Overall, though, Johnson seems to want to frame the discussion correctly as when he writes this:
The dystopian scenario, after all, isn’t about the death of the record business or Hollywood; it’s about the death of music or movies. As a society, what we most want to ensure is that the artists can prosper — not the record labels or studios or publishing conglomerates, but the writers, musicians, directors and actors themselves.
I agree. Despite being accused by my haters of wanting “the studios to be all powerful,” I don’t personally care if legacy corporations survive in their present form or not. But the Kool-Aid high Johnson seems to be on is one in which he can only see the short-term empowerment of some creators via these new technologies, but not the long-term, predatory nature of a brand new group of extraordinarily powerful, corporate masters. The MusicKey contract cited above is a clear example as to how YouTube could maneuver to become a monopsony for music streaming. So, how is that possibility better than having a handful of legacy labels and publishers? Also, if Johnson really does care, as I do, about preserving cultural diversity, then I am truly confused by this strangely dismissive statement:
The growth of live music isn’t great news for the Brian Wilsons of the world, artists who would prefer to cloister themselves in the studio, endlessly tinkering with the recording process in pursuit of a masterpiece.
It’s the words prefer and endlessly that are both offensive and naive. Plenty of professional musicians have already commented on the “growth in live music” myth, but this statement about Brian Wilson stuck out for me because it can only be a blatant reference to the album Pet Sounds — a recorded work so universally acclaimed as innovative that George Martin credited Wilson with inspiring Sgt. Peppers Lonely Hearts Club Band. Call me crazy, but I think we do lose something if the market cannot support both a Taylor Swift, who makes millions of screaming teenagers happy, and a reclusive, even dysfunctional, genius, who creates a recorded work of unprecedented and lasting value. It should also be noted that creative envelope-pushers like Wilson have consistently been the forces behind the invention of new technologies themselves. Think ILM and Star Wars.
Ultimately, Johnson is supporting an anti-copyright — and even pro-piracy — argument; but he seems to want to have his Cake and eat John McCrea’s lunch, too. And I say this because so much of the evidence for prosperity he offers — both economic and anecdotal — is largely dependent upon the framework of copyright. So, after leading off with a thesis that fundamentally begs a question about the seeds of piracy (i.e. Did it hurt us?), he winds up painting some pretty pictures, but never quite answers the question because so much of the good news he alludes to is antithetical to a market that ignores, tolerates, or even extolls the permission-free use of creative works. Because, as we see with examples like MusicKey or with the Internet industry’s willingness to monetize infringement while lobbying hard against creators’ rights, many creators themselves continue to discover that the Web giveth shortly before the Web taketh away.
Hence the question Johnson should be asking is not exclusively what the picture looks like right now (even if that picture is accurate), but whether or not the Internet industry is helping to foster a sustainable environment, not only for creators, but for non-creative enterprises as well. And although he is a much better writer than the tech-industry pundits, I don’t think he’s told a particularly compelling story just yet.
As both a musician and a communications consultant, I don’t even know where to start. From Napter to Uber, people have become obscenely rich through technologies that generate wealth without creating genuine and sustainable socioeconomic value. Then there is the fact that the going rate for bands in bars and clubs has been unchanged since the late ’70s. $300-$400 a night. Those brass rings of record company fame and fortune we tried to grab are long gone, and the carousels have been dismantled. Mr. Johnson is delusional.
David, are you drafting a rebuttal to submit to the NYT?
Thanks for asking, JT. I hadn’t really considered sending a rebuttal directly to the Times, though I won’t be surprised if someone in the creator rights community does. I’m sure mine won’t be the only blog response to the article, either. It will be interesting to see how this one trends, as they say.
Oh man, if I wasn’t up against a deadline for a project I’m working on, I would love to spend the weekend digging into this guy’s “data.”
Just at a glance, the OES 27-0000 group as a whole is a worthless indicator.
First, as pointed out in the original article, it include athletes, coaches, scouts, and referees. Coaches are surprisingly the largest of that, but then I remember all the high school athletics where the players certainly aren’t professional but the coaches are. These groups alone are going to heavily skew the income data.
Second, it includes lots of creative fields that couldn’t possibly be affected by the shift to digital, thus making their inclusion in the stats very… curious, to say the least. The first one that jumped out at me is “Floral Designer.” Now, I worked through part of college as a flower deliver guy and I know the design is an art, but it’s definitely not an art that could be threatened or much affected by the digital free-for-all. Going through the list, there are more like this. The inclusion of graphic designers as a whole, one of the larger groups, is iffy. That would include the guy that works for your local park agency who designs the brochures. Not to dismiss the craft, but that’s not what anyone was ever talking about when discussing the arts. Ditto “Merchandise Displayers and Window Trimmers.” I know people who do this here in NY, and it is lucrative and very artistic for some, but it also includes barely-above-minimum wage GAP staffers (which is reflected in the average wage stat).
Third, and this is something I’m not sure about, but music teachers are not included in the 27-0000 group, it would appear. That particular bit undoes the only part of the article where an actual musician is cited: that they are making money by giving lessons. Sorry, noble craft and all, but that makes you a teacher, not a professional musician. Even the BLS agrees, it would seem.
Don’t even get me started on self-reporting self-employed musicians. It’s not even worth trying to parse the real deals from the aspirants.
I’m just amazed that the NYT could let something like this hit the press without deeper fact checking. In particular, I love the part where the author says he has “one source” that says live music is booming for the mid-tier musicians. One?! As in, he could only find one, or he has other sources he doesn’t want to quote? Nevermind that he cites nothing. And for an article about the booming creative middle class, I’d figure he could find more than one(?) person to put in the article?
Anyway, a casual glance will show that in 1999 there were 46,000 people filing tax returns as musicians and singers, whereas in 2014 there were 38,900. A stat conveniently left out of the article you’ll notice. I think that speaks for itself.
Patrik, thanks for this. I had/have little doubt that the data are misleading but chose not to pursue that angle for this post. Still, very grateful for you taking even a cursory glance.
Great post David.
Thank you David
there’s another aspect of his “growth of live music” argument that isn’t mentioned: constant touring has been very hard physically on the new generation of performers. Lady Gaga, who in the last few years performed more shows than the Stones at their height, has had health problems, and Adele and others have had their voices strained beyond healthy levels.
But you really just have to look at the sheer output. Since 2008 Adele has released two studio albums, whereas Taylor Swift and Lady Gaga have both released four. compare that with The Beatles, who released 11 albums within a similar time period, or David Bowie, who released 10 – each album showing an astonishing level of growth. Which would you rather have – artists spending more time in the studio evolving their work, or artists playing the same hits over and over again?
It’s even worse for writers, who are not naturally inclined to public speaking. I’d rather have a George Simenon or Agatha Christie over a Neil Gaiman any day.
All true, and all good points. Thank you. As mentioned, each subject is a long discussion of its own, and touring is just one of them. The people who talk about touring have no idea what’s involved, especially for struggling or mid-level artist who have to do everything themselves. As if a singer/songwriter can create new works, tour all over the country, and maybe have a teaching YouTube channel all at the same time — and all for a living that won’t cover the medical bills when he has his first stroke.
Interestingly there was a study which showed that baby boomers rated themselves as healthier than they actually are. Maybe that’s trickled down to their offspring… and of course the tech people think they’ll be immortal…
What a wonderfully solid and eviscerating response to that train-wreck of Steven Johnson’s. Johnson brings up an interesting data point which I think is defensible, though his interpretation of it is not: That the overall revenues around creative work (music, books, and increasingly movies) are not necessarily diminishing. The problem is that those revenue streams have been redirected. AWAY from the content creators and to the content aggregators.
The recording industry as we knew it was more than anything an investment model. What’s changed is that instead of building a distribution/marketing business and investing in content to distribute, the tech industry vacuums up all that investment money for the distribution business, and just takes the content.
The “new model” may work for some very small percentage of artists…but it will never work for a songwriter who is not also a performer. Nor will it work for anyone in the broad spectrum of behind the scenes people who work on producing creative content. Many young folks coming up in the music business think it’s wonderful that they can produce an album of music using $2000 worth of tools, INCLUDING the generic use computer they’ve got…but the real value of the recording studio wasn’t the half-million-dollar console…it was the environment itself.
Thank you for one of the more succinct summations of the difference between the old and new models of music making. The digital workstation cannot conjure up the magic that comes from a great day in the studio with dedicated musicians and an accomplished engineer. Those days when a finished song turns out better than it has any right to be are the ones that have made it all worthwhile.
“..the overall revenues around creative work….are not necessarily diminishing.”
I heavily question this. Basically the economics of this statement boil down to saying “internet ad revenue is as high as (pre-internet) sales revenue”. I seriously don’t think this is true at all. Now, an individual or small group can get rich off a pirate site, but their revenues will usually be a tiny fraction of what a record/production company’s revenue would have been. They are able to get rich because their cost of inventory is 0.
Add this to a tech stock bubble and a (until very recently) still incredibly resilient cable industry and I think it can look like the money’s still there. It would certainly make things easier. “The money’s still there, it just has to be routed properly!” Is a much easier fix than “The money’s gone.” Unfortunately I think the latter is probably true. The former, unfortunately, is the new version of 1999’s :I think Napster will only increase sales!”
I think it’s probably far more appropriate to use the words “cash flows” than the word “revenue.” I think that more aptly captures what I’m trying to say…that the sector is drowning in venture capital money, but skant little of it is going to content creation/creators.
OK. That makes slightly more sense. But venture capital money is ephemeral. It chases one thing: returns. Those returns can come two ways:via actually creating a great business with revenue or via the Greater Fool. The actual good businesses that involve content creation are vanishing. So its no surprise that content creators aren’t getting the money (I wouldn’t give it to them if I ran a venture fund! ). That leaves the Greater Fool. But that only works for so long before the Fool realizes he’s not standing on anything.
In short, while plenty of wealth gets passed around in the short term, venture funding is only really works for an industry if it’s a bridge to a real business. And I don’t see that business anywhere unless the government actually starts enforcing copyright. Do you? If so, where?
“The Creative Apocalypse that Wasn’t” has received over 200 comments with the consensus running 20 to 1 that the article is seriously flawed with little or no resemblance to the real world of working artists. It reminds one of the 2012 distortion “The Sky is Rising The Entertainment Industry Is Large & Growing… Not Shrinking”
which was soundly discredited at the time for inaccuracies and flawed logic.
Another thorough, scholarly rebuttal from Mr. Newhoff.
Thank you sir.
Excellent response David. Johnson’s assessment just doesn’t reflect the situation on the ground. The post-Napster creative destruction, from the artist’s perspective, has been seriously biased toward destruction.
The only thing that really matters–and Johnson makes this point at the end–is that we need to find new ways for artists to make money. The current channels yield insufficient revenue, reward platforms over creators, and are based on models like touring or online advertising that are extremely difficult to sustain.
This has always been a problem–Melville worked as a custom agent to pay his bills–but we can do better.
Are you done masturbating, David? Jesus. Knock if off. You sound like a loser. Not once in your article, you mention a way to go forward. (It’s always easy to criticize someone than to come up with your own solution) Of course, it will be great if the music industry has a change of heart and caters to musicians “based on the data” or on the “reality” of “real” musicians. But that just isn’t a reality. I’m not suggesting that we let tech industry and music labels rob us of our profits, but that bashing someone just because he takes a different position and rebutting really minor issues won’t push anything forward unless you have your own solutions to proffer. Steven Johnson’s article, at least to me, seems to be saying “there is a bright side to all this.” It’s not all doom and gloom. Yes, he admits that it may not be for everyone. But that’s not the point of the article.
Listen, the creative industries, not just music, is facing a tough economic and cultural landscape. No one is suggesting that we are all the better… but that main thing at issue is that no one is dying either, unless if you choose to. The change we are going through will happen whether you like it or not, but that in the end, and through the big shift, there are also opportunities here for musicians to thrive. You may not like this aspect, nor should you, but the fact remains that there are musicians who are benefiting from this shift, which is the point of the article.
“I don’t think he’s told a particularly compelling story just yet.” Really? He’s writing an article for a newspaper with a limited space, less than 6 thousand words. Do you really expect him to write a “compelling story” in that space? And what would that “story” be? A list of disgruntled musicians because of the internet age? And from whose perspective? The “real” musicians? He mentions over and over that, yes, they are downsides to this shift, as in any industry when a new mode of doing things is introduced. You are complaining about things this article is not about.
This would have been a much better rebuttal had Mr. Newhoff employed a tone of respect and less self-aggrandizement, and this tone of “oh, those good old days…” Get over it! We are in a different age with a different mindset. As it is, it sounds like a kid whining about not getting the pony he wanted, albeit with a little bit of “supposed” analysis thrown in to justify why he must.
Well channie, on the subject of masturbatory whining, I’m glad you got that off your chest, but it’s clear to me that you neither understood Mr. Johnson’s article nor my rebuttal. But since 6,000 words is ample room to write a compelling story, and I devoted nearly 3,000 in response, I’m certainly not going to waste another few hundred attempting to explain what you missed, either in tone or substance. But thanks for sharing.
Actually there is a “new mode of doing things” there is a new and more efficient way of robbing. Effectively what is being praised is the replacement of the bludgeon with the semi-automatic pistol for the purpose.